Economics isn't ideology-free and it's misleading to suggest it is

Trying to answer policy questions with economics is bound to involve ideology

Graham White | The Conversation 

Photo: Shutterstock
Photo: Shutterstock

Prime Minister recently commented that when it comes to Australia’s energy supply:

“policymakers have put and politics ahead of engineering and economics”.

It’s not uncommon for a politician to accuse other of being subservient to on some issue. But to couch this accusation in terms of a choice between “the economics” or “just ideology” is problematic.

We should be highly sceptical of claims that the pronouncements of economists about real world economic problems stand above any ideological influence. This might in turn allow for a more sober assessment of what can and can’t deliver.

There’s a belief, still present within the profession and which still finds its way into the of undergraduate students, that possesses a box of tools that are value-free, or ideologically uncontaminated. And that somehow this allows for economic statements about real that are free of

The idea persists in part because it serves a purpose, for some, in providing a benchmark for measuring the “scientific progress” of as an intellectual discipline.

But things are less clear when you look more closely at how the box of tools is used.

Take the proposition, for example, that lower prices for goods and services would benefit the consumer, using some measure of consumer welfare. Or that increased competition would under certain conditions lead to lower prices.

Leaving aside the fact that the choice of measure of consumer welfare might itself not be completely untainted by ideology, using these propositions to diagnose real inevitably brings into play.

For example, justifying a to promote “efficiencies” in production as a means of achieving lower prices, which might also require people losing their jobs, would warrant some additional reasoning about society’s objectives underpinning the production and distribution of its material wealth.

This is especially the case where the economic toolbox does not support a belief that market mechanisms would automatically kick in to provide employment for displaced workers. prescription in this case is inevitably ideologically laden.

The tool box can also contain, for example, propositions about how the size of the federal government’s budget deficit, the speed at which the economy is growing and the path of public debt over time are all connected.

To turn such propositions into meaningful discussions of economic policy, particularly about government spending, taxation or welfare outlays, requires additional propositions that are likely to be conditioned by This includes the amount of public debt a country should live with and, more fundamentally, what activities governments should be involved in.

For 20th-century economist Maurice Dobb, enters into the picture as soon as we put the box of tools to work.

In other words, a set of formal economic propositions could only be considered immune from prior to being used as a means of illuminating real But arguably, as Dobb suggests, at this stage the box of tools has little economic content.

But as soon as these propositions are used to infer cause and effect, and in turn form a basis for prescription, inevitably enters into the picture.

Indeed, for some, even decisions about which tools go into the tool box are not completely free of

The point of all this is not that we should throw up our arms in despair at the influence of in To quote the Austrian economist and historian of economic thought Joseph Schumpeter:

“explanation, however correct, of the reasons why a man says what he says tells us nothing about whether it is true or false”.

and intertwine. This serves as a reminder that the use of economic propositions for diagnosis and prescription can be affected by a historically conditioned vision of how things are and “the way in which we wish to see them” (to borrow Schumpeter’s terminology).


Graham White, Associate Professor, School of Economics, University of Sydney

This article was originally published on The Conversation. Read the original article.

The Conversation

Economics isn't ideology-free and it's misleading to suggest it is

Trying to answer policy questions with economics is bound to involve ideology

Trying to answer policy questions with economics is bound to involve ideology

Prime Minister recently commented that when it comes to Australia’s energy supply:

“policymakers have put and politics ahead of engineering and economics”.

It’s not uncommon for a politician to accuse other of being subservient to on some issue. But to couch this accusation in terms of a choice between “the economics” or “just ideology” is problematic.

We should be highly sceptical of claims that the pronouncements of economists about real world economic problems stand above any ideological influence. This might in turn allow for a more sober assessment of what can and can’t deliver.

There’s a belief, still present within the profession and which still finds its way into the of undergraduate students, that possesses a box of tools that are value-free, or ideologically uncontaminated. And that somehow this allows for economic statements about real that are free of

The idea persists in part because it serves a purpose, for some, in providing a benchmark for measuring the “scientific progress” of as an intellectual discipline.

But things are less clear when you look more closely at how the box of tools is used.

Take the proposition, for example, that lower prices for goods and services would benefit the consumer, using some measure of consumer welfare. Or that increased competition would under certain conditions lead to lower prices.

Leaving aside the fact that the choice of measure of consumer welfare might itself not be completely untainted by ideology, using these propositions to diagnose real inevitably brings into play.

For example, justifying a to promote “efficiencies” in production as a means of achieving lower prices, which might also require people losing their jobs, would warrant some additional reasoning about society’s objectives underpinning the production and distribution of its material wealth.

This is especially the case where the economic toolbox does not support a belief that market mechanisms would automatically kick in to provide employment for displaced workers. prescription in this case is inevitably ideologically laden.

The tool box can also contain, for example, propositions about how the size of the federal government’s budget deficit, the speed at which the economy is growing and the path of public debt over time are all connected.

To turn such propositions into meaningful discussions of economic policy, particularly about government spending, taxation or welfare outlays, requires additional propositions that are likely to be conditioned by This includes the amount of public debt a country should live with and, more fundamentally, what activities governments should be involved in.

For 20th-century economist Maurice Dobb, enters into the picture as soon as we put the box of tools to work.

In other words, a set of formal economic propositions could only be considered immune from prior to being used as a means of illuminating real But arguably, as Dobb suggests, at this stage the box of tools has little economic content.

But as soon as these propositions are used to infer cause and effect, and in turn form a basis for prescription, inevitably enters into the picture.

Indeed, for some, even decisions about which tools go into the tool box are not completely free of

The point of all this is not that we should throw up our arms in despair at the influence of in To quote the Austrian economist and historian of economic thought Joseph Schumpeter:

“explanation, however correct, of the reasons why a man says what he says tells us nothing about whether it is true or false”.

and intertwine. This serves as a reminder that the use of economic propositions for diagnosis and prescription can be affected by a historically conditioned vision of how things are and “the way in which we wish to see them” (to borrow Schumpeter’s terminology).


Graham White, Associate Professor, School of Economics, University of Sydney

This article was originally published on The Conversation. Read the original article.

The Conversation
image
Business Standard
177 22